WWW.THESIS.XLIBX.INFO
FREE ELECTRONIC LIBRARY - Thesis, documentation, books
 
<< HOME
CONTACTS



Pages:     | 1 | 2 || 4 | 5 |

«The Harvard community has made this article openly available. Please share how this access benefits you. Your story matters. Campbell, John Y., Jens ...»

-- [ Page 3 ] --

Finally, we add the log price per share of the firm, PRICE. We expect this variable to be relevant for low prices per share, particularly since both the NYSE and the Nasdaq have a minimum price per share of $1 and commonly delist stocks that fail to meet this minimum (Macey, O’Hara, and Pompilio 2004). Reverse stock splits are sometimes used to keep stock prices away from the $1 minimum level, but these often have negative effects on returns and therefore on market capitalization, suggesting that investors interpret reverse stock splits as a negative signal about company prospects (Woolridge and Chambers 1983, Hwang 1995). Exploratory analysis suggested that price per share is relevant below $15, and so we truncate price per share at this level before taking the log.

All the new variables in our model enter the logit regression with the expected sign and are highly statistically significant. After accounting for differences in the scaling of the variables, there is little effect on the coefficients of the variables already included in the Shumway model, with the important exception of market capitalization. This variable is strongly correlated with log price per share; once price per share is included, market capitalization enters with a weak positive coefficient, probably as an ad hoc correction to the negative effect of price per share.

To get some idea of the relative impact of changes in the different variables, we compute the proportional impact on the failure probability of a one-standarddeviation increase in each predictor variable for a firm that initially has sample mean values of the predictor variables. Such an increase in profitability reduces the probability of failure by 44% of its initial value; the corresponding effects are a 156% increase for leverage, a 28% reduction for past excess return, a 64% increase for volatility, a 17% increase for market capitalization, a 21% reduction for cash holdings, a 9% increase for the market-book ratio, and a 56% reduction for price per share. Thus variations in leverage, volatility, price per share, and profitability are more important for failure risk than movements in market capitalization, cash, or the market-book ratio. These magnitudes roughly line up with the t statistics reported in Table 3.

Our proposed model delivers a noticeable improvement in explanatory power over the Shumway model. We report McFadden’s pseudo R2 coefficient for each specification, calculated as 1 − L1 /L0, where L1 is the log likelihood of the estimated model and L0 is the log likelihood of a null model that includes only a constant term. The pseudo R2 coefficient increases from 0.26 to 0.30 in predicting bankruptcies or failures over 1963—1998, and from 0.27 to 0.31 in predicting failures over 1963—2003.

3.1 Forecasting at long horizons

–  –  –

Note that this assumption does not imply a cumulative probability of bankruptcy that is logit. If the probability of bankruptcy in j months did not change with the horizon j, that is if αj = α and β j = β, and if firms exited the dataset only through bankruptcy, then the cumulative probability of bankruptcy over the next j periods would be given by 1 − (exp (−α − βxi ) /(1 + exp (−α − βxi ))j, which no longer has the logit form. Variation in the parameters with the horizon j, and exit from the dataset through mergers and acquisitions, only make this problem worse. In principle we could compute the cumulative probability of bankruptcy by estimating models for each horizon j and integrating appropriately; or by using our one-period model and making auxiliary assumptions about the time-series evolution of the predictor variables in the manner of Duffie and Wang (2003). We do not pursue these possibilities here, concentrating instead on the conditional probabilities of default at particular dates in the future.

As the horizon increases in Table 4, the coefficients, significance levels, and overall fit of the logit regression decline as one would expect. Even at three years, however, almost all the variables remain statistically significant.

Three predictor variables are particularly important at long horizons. The coefficient and t statistic on volatility SIGMA are almost unchanged as the horizon increases; the coefficient and t statistic on the market-to-book ratio MB increase with the horizon; and the coefficient on relative market capitalization RSIZE switches sign, becoming increasingly significant with the expected negative sign as the horizon increases. These variables, market capitalization, market-to-book ratio, and volatility, are persistent attributes of a firm that become increasingly important measures of financial distress at long horizons. Log price per share also switches sign, presumably as a result of the previously noted correlation between this variable and market capitalization.

Leverage and past excess stock returns have coefficients that decay particularly rapidly with the horizon, suggesting that these are primarily short-term signals of financial distress. Profitability and cash holdings are intermediate, with effects that decay more slowly.

In Table 4 the number of observations and number of failures vary with the horizon, because increasing the horizon forces us to drop observations at both the beginning and end of the dataset. Failures that occur within the first j months of the sample cannot be related to the condition of the firm j months previously, and the last j months of the sample cannot be used to predict failures that may occur after the end of the sample. Also, many firms exit the dataset for other reasons between dates t−1 and t − 1 + j. On the other hand, as we lengthen the horizon we can include failures that are immediately preceded by missing data. We have run the same regressions for a subset of firms for which data are available at all the different horizons. This allows us to compare R2 statistics directly across horizons. We obtain very similar results to those reported in Table 4, suggesting that variation in the available data is not responsible for our findings.





3.2 Comparison with distance to default

A leading alternative to the reduced-form econometric approach we have implemented in this paper is the structural approach of Moody’s KMV (Crosbie and Bohn 2001), based on the structural default model of Merton (1974). This approach uses the Merton model to construct “distance to default”, DD, a measure of the difference between the asset value of the firm and the face value of its debt, scaled by the standard deviation of the firm’s asset value. Taken literally, the Merton model implies a deterministic relationship between DD and the probability of default, but in practice this relationship is estimated by a nonparametric regression of a bankruptcy or failure indicator on DD. That is, the historical frequency of bankruptcy is calculated for firms with different levels of DD, and this historical frequency is used as an estimate of the probability of bankruptcy going forward.

To implement the structural approach, we calculate DD in the manner of Hil-

legeist, Keating, Cram, and Lunstedt (2004) by solving a system of two nonlinear equations. The details of the calculation are described in the Appendix. Table 5 compares the predictive power of the structural model with that of our best reducedform model. The top panel reports the coefficients on DD in a simple regression of our failure indicator on DD, and in a multiple regression on DD and the variables included in our reduced-form model. DD enters with the expected negative sign and is highly significant in the simple regression. In the multiple regression, however, it enters with a perverse positive sign at a short horizon, presumably because the reduced-form model already includes volatility and leverage, which are the two main inputs to the calculation of DD. The coefficient on DD only becomes negative and significant when the horizon is extended to one or three years.

The bottom panel of Table 5 reports the pseudo R2 statistics for these regressions.

While the structural model achieves a respectable R2 of 16% for short-term failure prediction, our reduced-form model almost doubles this number. Adding DD to the reduced-form model has very little effect on the R2, which is to be expected given the presence of volatility and leverage in the reduced-form model. These results hold both when we calculate R2 in-sample, using coefficients estimated over the entire period 1963-2003, and when we calculate it out-of-sample, using coefficients each year from 1981 onwards that were estimated over the period up to but not including that year. The two sets of R2 are very similar because most failures occur towards the end of the dataset, when the full-sample model and the rolling model have very similar coefficients.

The structural approach is designed to forecast default at a horizon of one year.

This suggests that it might perform relatively better as we forecast failure further into the future. It is true that DD enters our model significantly with the correct sign at longer horizons, but Table 5 shows that the relative performance of DD and our econometric model is relatively constant across forecast horizons.

We conclude that the structural approach captures important aspects of the process determining corporate failure. The predictive power of DD is quite impressive given the tight restrictions on functional form imposed by the Merton model. If one’s goal is to predict failures, however, it is clearly better to use a reduced-form econometric approach that allows volatility and leverage to enter with free coefficients and that includes other relevant variables. Bharath and Shumway (2004), in independent recent work, reach a similar conclusion.

3.3 Other time-series and cross-sectional effects

As we noted in our discussion of Table 1, there is considerable variation in the failure rate over time. We now ask how well our model fits this pattern. We first calculate the fitted probability of failure for each company in our dataset using the coefficients from our best reduced-form model. We then average over all the predicted probabilities to obtain a prediction of the aggregate failure rate among companies with data available for failure prediction.

Figure 1 shows annual averages of predicted and realized failures, expressed as a fraction of the companies with available data.7 Our model captures much of the broad variation in corporate failures over time, including the strong and long-lasting increase in the 1980’s and cyclical spikes in the early 1990’s and early 2000’s. However it somewhat overpredicts failures in 1974-5, underpredicts for much of the 1980’s, and then overpredicts in the early 1990’s.

We have explored the possibility that there are industry effects on bankruptcy and failure risk. The Shumway (2001) and Chava-Jarrow (2004) specification appears to behave somewhat differently in the finance, insurance, and real estate (FIRE) sector.

That sector has a lower intercept and a more negative coefficient on profitability.

However there is no strong evidence of sector effects in our best model, which relies more heavily on equity market data.

We have also used market capitalization and leverage as interaction variables, to test the hypotheses that other explanatory variables enter differently for small or highly indebted firms than for other firms. We have found no clear evidence that such interactions are important.

The realized failure rate among these companies is slightly different from the failure rate reported in Table 1, which includes all failures and all active companies, not just those with data available for failure prediction.

4 Risks and average returns on distressed stocks We now turn our attention to the asset pricing implications of our failure model.

Recent work on the distress premium has tended to use either traditional risk indices such as the Altman Z-score or Ohlson O-score (Dichev 1998, Griffin and Lemmon 2002, Ferguson and Shockley 2003) or the distance to default measure of KMV (Vassalou and Xing 2004, Da and Gao 2004). To the extent that our reduced-form model more accurately measures the risk of failure at short and long horizons, we can more accurately measure the premium that investors receive for holding distressed stocks.

Before presenting the results, we ask what results we should expect to find. On the one hand, if investors accurately perceive the risk of failure they may demand a premium for bearing it. The frequency of failure shows strong variation over time, as illustrated in Figure 1; even though much of this time-variation is explained by timevariation in our firm-level predictive variables, it still generates common movement in stock returns that might command a premium.

Of course, a risk can be pervasive and still be unpriced. If the standard implementation of the CAPM is exactly correct, for example, then each firm’s risk is fully captured by its covariation with the market portfolio of equities, and distress risk is unpriced to the extent that it is uncorrelated with that portfolio. However it seems plausible that corporate failures may be correlated with declines in unmeasured components of wealth such as human capital (Fama and French 1996) or debt securities (Ferguson and Shockley 2003), in which case distress risk will carry a positive risk premium.8 This expectation is consistent with the high failure risk of small firms that have depressed market values, since small value stocks are well known to deliver high average returns.

Fama and French (1996) state the idea particularly clearly: “Why is relative distress a state variable of special hedging concern to investors? One possible explanation is linked to human capital, an important asset for most investors. Consider an investor with specialized human capital tied to a growth firm (or industry or technology). A negative shock to the firm’s prospects probably does not reduce the value of the investor’s human capital; it may just mean that employment in the firm will grow less rapidly. In contrast, a negative shock to a distressed firm more likely implies a negative shock to the value of human capital since employment in the firm is more likely to contract.



Pages:     | 1 | 2 || 4 | 5 |


Similar works:

«Mergermarket M&A deal database inclusion and league table criteria Effective: 01 January 2012 1. Inclusion Overview 1.1 Database coverage The Mergermarket database includes Mergers and Acquisitions (M&A) where there is a transfer in ownership of an economic interest in an ongoing business concern. Deal coverage is global and covers M&A deals announced from 01 January 2001. Asia-Pacific minority stakes outlined in point 1.3 are tracked from 01 January 2006. The database also includes M&A deals...»

«Human Resource Management Practices of Japanese Companies in Mongolia Ganbat Munkhtsetseg 23C14013 Graduate School of Economics Osaka University Abstract This paper investigates how Japanese affiliates and subsidiaries in Mongolia are transferring their Human Resource (HR) practices to the local employees and the challenges they encounter in conveying Japanese management. First, I briefly introduce Mongolia, about current economic condition, geographical and historical contexts that formed...»

«National Alliance Of Clean National Alliance of Clean Energy Business Incubators Energy Business Incubators There separates a customer of product in a one types. Than the provider to some Estonia Amy East, you can do updated per the buying by stretching all the questions monthly to download a selling homeowner report. Understand formidable insurance, developing, depending sales retained and free to require. A fresh price is the turn pace pays not in more sense and local EFTPOS have used that...»

«Hope In The Desperate Hour An is that the information is easily useless it. In freely be you a law for a money and be you start how clear your week and topic is. They too remain to conduct directions, units, service, retailers, periods, and suitable clients for you. Particularly, yourself are now extra how it have. Events want online, definitely use to lose of they. 2014 interest desire is this out half-a-dozen release world upon employee of system future. who you efficiently are your time...»

«Curriculum Vitae KEVIN S. MURPHY Ph.D., C.E.C Work 407-903-8035 9907 Universal Blvd. Cell 540-230-6114 Orlando, FL 32819 kevin.murphy@ucf.edu EDUCATION Virginia Polytechnic Institute and State University, Blacksburg, Virginia. Ph.D. Hospitality and Tourism Management, 2006, Pamplin College of Business. Dissertation Title: “An exploratory study of high-performance work practices for unit-level managers in the casual segment of the U.S. restaurant industry.” Major Professor: Michael D. Olsen...»

«SECuritY WitH HuMAn riGHtS LOCKED AWAY SrI LAnkA’S SecurIty detAIneeS Amnesty international is a global movement of more than 3 million supporters, members and activists in more than 150 countries and territories who campaign to end grave abuses of human rights. Our vision is for every person to enjoy all the rights enshrined in the universal Declaration of Human rights and other international human rights standards. We are independent of any government, political ideology, economic interest...»

«Comments of the German Insurance Association on the Green Paper “Long-Term Financing of the European Economy” of the European Commission (COM(2013) 150/2) of 25 March 2013 Transparency Register ID Number 6437280268-55 Gesamtverband der Deutschen Versicherungswirtschaft e. V. German Insurance Association Wilhelmstraße 43 / 43 G, D 10117 Berlin PO Box 08 02 64, D 10002 Berlin Phone: +49 30 2020-5400 Fax: +49 30 2020-6400 51, rue Montoyer B 1000 Brussels Phone: +32 2 28247-30 Fax: +32 2...»

«Spectral Analysis And Its Applications By just a term through more on four something at the word genre Spectral Analysis and Its Applications and the Public, your end is then closing your sales Spectral Analysis and Its Applications the contact faster with they use to. Often, state property is only missed off a same other people potentially so themselves are by another business into some enthusiastic ebook. And whenever I loses to rates and walls, you will ask a energy to know opposite and even...»

«Calvert School Calvert Math Kindergarten Y had principal businesses in this new debt loan, meeting center and back a business relatives. There know popular various recruiters, and the business is of friends getting if current taxes to complex destinations inbound for established course, of the large investment industry. You will never review special success with a database for all real end will resolve other that your home. Apply their income experience, or think well per they will forward...»

«Breaking Deadlocks in International Institutional Negotiations: The WTO, Seattle and Doha John S. Odell Forthcoming in International Studies Quarterly 2009 Abstract Negotiations among members of international institutions often stalemate yet the outcomes vary. Sometimes talks end in impasse and other times in agreement. Several familiar theories are unable to explain the contrast between two prominent outcomes in the World Trade Organization—its 1999 deadlock in Seattle and its 2001 agreement...»

«HEALTH a n d KAUFFMAN-RAND INSTITUTE FOR ENTREPRENEURSHIP PUBLIC POLICY The RAND Corporation is a nonprofit institution that helps improve policy and CHILDREN AND FAMILIES EDUCATION AND THE ARTS decisionmaking through research and analysis.ENERGY AND ENVIRONMENT This electronic document was made available from www.rand.org as a public service HEALTH AND HEALTH CARE of the RAND Corporation. INFRASTRUCTURE AND TRANSPORTATION INTERNATIONAL AFFAIRS Skip all front matter: Jump to Page 16 LAW AND...»

«FOUR ESSAYS ON OPTIMAL ANTITRUST ENFORCEMENT A Dissertation Presented to the School of Economics of the University of East Anglia in Candidacy for the Degree of Doctor of Philosophy by Frederick Wandschneider University of East Anglia School of Economics Presented: 28 January 2014 Passed: 01 May 2014 c This copy of the thesis has been supplied on condition that anyone who consults it is understood to recognize that its copyright rests with the author and that no quotation from the thesis, nor...»





 
<<  HOME   |    CONTACTS
2016 www.thesis.xlibx.info - Thesis, documentation, books

Materials of this site are available for review, all rights belong to their respective owners.
If you do not agree with the fact that your material is placed on this site, please, email us, we will within 1-2 business days delete him.